The Chinese yuan has appreciated by more than 27.5% since 2005, when
the People’s Bank of China (“PBOC”) formally acceded to international
pressure and began to relax the yuan-dollar peg. For China-watchers
and economists, that the Yuan will continue to appreciate is thus a
given. There is no question of
if, but rather of
when and
to what extent.
But what if the prevailing wisdom is wrong? What if the yuan is now
fairly valued, and economic fundamentals no longer necessitate a
further rise?

Prior to the 2005 revaluation, economists had argued that the yuan (also known as the Chinese RMB) was
undervalued by 15% – 40%,
and American politicians had used this as a basis for proposing a
27.5% across-the-board tariff on all Chinese imports. Given that the
yuan has now appreciated by this exact margin (and by even more when
inflation is taken into account), shouldn’t this alone be enough to
silence the critics, without even having to look at the picture on the
ground? How can Senator Charles Schumer
continue to press for further appreciation
when the yuan’s rise exceeds his initial demands? Alas, election
season is upon us, and we can’t hope to make political sense out of
this issue. We can, however, attempt to analyze the economic sense of
it.
China manipulates the value of the yuan in order to give a
competitive advantage to Chinese exporters, goes the conventional line
of thinking. Look no further than the Chinese trade surplus for evidence
of this, right? As it turns out, China’s trade surplus is shrinking
rapidly. In 2006, it was a whopping 11% of GDP. Last year, it had
fallen to 5%, and it is
projected by the World Bank
to settle below 3% for each of the next two years. Thanks to a first
quarter trade deficit – the first in over seven years – China’s trade
surplus may account for a negligible portion (~.2%) of GDP growth in
2010.

With this in mind, why would the PBOC even think about allowing the
RMB to appreciate further? According to one perspective, the narrowing
trade imbalance is only temporary. When commodities prices settle and
global demand fully recovers, a wider trade surplus will follow. In
fact, the IMF forecasts China’s current surplus will rise to 8% by
2016. As you can see from the chart below (courtesy of
The Economist),
however, the IMF’s forecasts have proven to be too pessimistic for at
least the last three years, and it now has very little credibility.
Besides, China’s economy is gradually reorienting itself away from
exports and towards domestic spending. As a resident of China, I can
certainly attest to this phenomenon, and the last few years has seen an
explosion in the number of cars on the road, domestic tourism, and
conspicuous consumption.

A better argument for further RMB appreciation comes in the form of
inflation. At 5.4%, inflation is officially nearing a 3-year high, and
there is evidence that the
PBOC already recognizes that allowing the RMB to keep rising represents its best tool for containing this problem. It has
already raised banks’
required reserve ratio
several times, but there is a limit to what this can accomplish.
Meanwhile, the PBOC remains reluctant to raise interest rates because
it will invite further
“hot-money” inflows (estimated at more than $100 Billion per year, if not much higher) and potentially
destabilize the banking sector. By raising the value of the yuan, the PBOC can blunt the impact of
rising commodities prices and other inflationary forces.
In fact, some think that the PBOC will quicken the pace of
appreciation, a view that as supported by last month’s .9% rise. Others
think that a once-off appreciation would be more effective, and is
hence more likely. This would not only remove the motivation for
further hot-money inflows, but would also reduce the PBOC’s need to
continue accumulating foreign exchange reserves. At $3 trillion+
($1.15 trillion of which are held in US Treasury Securities), these
reserves are already a massive headache for policymakers. Merely
stating the obvious, PBOC Governor Zhou Xiaochuan has officially
called the reserves “
really too much.” (It’s worth pointing out that the promotion of the yuan as an international currency is
backfiring in some ways, causing the reserves to balloon even faster).

For the record, I think that the Chinese yuan is pretty close to being
fairly valued. That might seem like a ridiculous claim to make when
Chinese wages and prices are still well below the global average.
Consider, however, that the same is true for the majority of emerging
market economies, including those that don’t peg their currencies to
the dollar. That doesn’t mean that the yuan won’t – or that it shouldn’t
– continue to rise. In fact, the PBOC needs to do more to ensure that
the Yuan appreciates evenly against all currencies, since most of the
yuan’s rise to-date has taken place relative to the US Dollar. It’s
merely a commentary that the PBOC is close to fulfilling the promises
it has made regarding the yuan, and going forward, I think that
observers should expect that its forex policy will be reconfigured to
promote domestic macroeconomic policy objectives.
No comments:
Post a Comment