Most of the recent discussion surrounding foreign exchange reserves
has focused on the allocation of those reserves; specifically, whether
or not these reserves will be invested in Dollar-denominated assets to
the same extent as before. But what if this discussion fails to see the
forest through the trees? In other words, this issue is built on the
implicit premise that Central Banks will continue to build their forex
reserves, and hence they need a place to invest them. With this post, I
will examine whether this is indeed the case.
Since the start of the credit crisis, forex reserve growth has slowed
as Central Banks (mainly in emerging markets) began to deploy some of
their cash: “In the first quarter of 2009, foreign reserves were at 80%
of their June 2008 levels in Korea and India, around 75% in Poland and
65% in Russia.” Most of the spending was used for direct intervention in
currency markets and to finance capital outflows, as risk-averse
investors moved funds out of emerging markets. Russia, alone, spent
nearly $200 Billion trying to prevent a complete collapse in confidence
in the Ruble.
Thanks to their prudence following the 1997 Southeast Asian economic
crisis, however, reserves are still more than adequate based on most
measures: “A well known rule of thumb (the so-called Guidotti-Greenspan
rule) is that foreign reserves should cover 100% of external debt coming
due within one year. In 2008, almost all EMEs far exceeded this
threshold – coverage was more than 400% in Asia and Russia and around
300% in Latin America. Another rule of thumb, that foreign reserves
should cover three to six months of imports (ie 25–50% of annual
imports) was also typically exceeded at the end of 2008.” Even despite
the recent declines, coverage remains strong enough to meet financing
requirements for the immediate future. China, whose cache of forex is by
far the world’s largest, boasts a coverage ratio of nearly 2,000%!
Given
such robustness, it’s clear that the impetus to continue accumulating
reserves has eroded slightly. Central Banks have also come to realize
how vulnerable they are to credit and currency risk, vis-a-vis the
allocation of their reserves, which means that the best alternative
going forward is probably to start investing in commodities and/or
domestic economic initiatives. China has already begun to move in this
direction.
There are several alternatives that are less risky/expensive than
directly holding foreign exchange reserves. “First, in October 2008 four
EME central banks each entered into a $30 billion reciprocal currency
arrangement with the US Federal Reserve. Second, a $120 billion
multilateral facility, drawing on international reserves, was recently
established in East Asia…Third, recent G20 initiatives have called for
large increases in resources for international financial
institutions…[such as the] IMF’s recently created Flexible Credit Line.”
Such programs provide countries in crisis with the cash to draw from
without forcing them to build up reserves in advance.
To be fair, not all Central Banks are prepared to break from the
current system. “In spite of significant interventions in the fourth
quarter of 2008, many EMEs still had larger foreign reserves at the end
of 2008 than they did in 2007.” Reports are coming in that Indian and Korean
reserves, for example, have reached their highest levels since the
collapse of Lehman Brothers last fall. This is sounding alarm bells for
economic officials: “There is a hope the lesson taken away from the
current experience is not that these countries need even larger foreign
exchange reserves. These things are not terribly efficient. Our concern is that these things are going to be built up even further as a consequence.”
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment